A Partial General Equilibrium Analysis of Fiscal Policy Injection on Poverty and Inequality in South Africa



Kambale Kavese1, Andrew Phiri2



Abstract: This study employs a partial general equilibrium approach calibrated on the Social Accounting Matrix (SAM) and a contemporaneous dynamic computable general equilibrium (CGE) model to assess the effect of expansionary fiscal policy on economic growth, income inequality, poverty, employment and inequality reduction in South Africa. The simulation results reveal that expansionary fiscal policy i) benefits rich ‘white’ households the most and poor ‘coloured’ households the least ii) improves adult employment more than youth employment iii) improves employment in urban areas as proposed to employment in rural areas iv) has a very small effect on improving economic growth and reducing the Gini coefficient v) benefits ‘well-off’ households more than it does ‘poor’ households vi) promotes ‘low-skilled’ employment more than it does for ‘high-skilled’ labourers. Associated policy implications based on our findings are also discussed.

Keywords: Social accounting matrix (SAM); Computable General Equilibrium (CGE); New Development Plan (NDP); Inequality; Poverty; Employment; South Africa

JEL Classification: C68; D58; E16; I32



1. Introduction

Despite recently celebrating just over 25 years of democracy, South Africa remains a country highly divided along racial lines, with one of the highest Gini coefficients in the World (Collins et al., 2019). From the onset of being liberated from the former oppressive Apartheid regime in 1994, South Africa’s ANC government has dedicated large fiscal spending towards eradicating the ‘big three’ social ills namely poverty, unemployment and inequality. In retrospect, South African fiscal authorities have conjured a handful of social expenditure programmes such as the Reconstruction and Development Programme (RDP) in 1994, Growth, Employment and Re-distribution (GEAR) programme in 1996, Accelerated and Shared Growth Initiative South Africa (ASGISA) in 2003, Millennium Development Goals (MDG) in 2010, the New Growth Path (NGP) in 2011 and the most recent New Development Programme (NDP)-Vision 2030 introduced in 2014. Collectively, these social spending programmes set-out specific macroeconomic targets such as attaining a 6 percent annual economic growth rate, halving of the unemployment rate by 2020 through job creation as well as eradicating poverty by 2030 and, so far fiscal authorities have had little success in attaining these macroeconomic objectives.

Internationally, the World Bank (2018) has recently ranked South Africa as the most unequal country in the world, coupled with post-recession slow growth trajectory and high levels of poverty. The World Bank (2018) describes poverty in South Africa has having a ‘strong spatial dimension’ which demonstrates the enduring legacy of apartheid, and setback of marginalised groups of people. The groups worst affected by poverty are the black population‚ the youth‚ the less educated‚ female-headed households‚ large families and children. For example, the top 1% of South Africans own 70.9% of the country’s wealth while the bottom 60% only controls 7% of the country’s assets. More than half of South Africans (55.5%) people live below the national poverty line of R992 per month (World Bank, 2018). Altogether, poverty in South Africa has multiple dimensions and its depths can vary when assessed by race (African vs non-African), income (less privileged v privileged households), age (youth vs adult), area (urban v non-urban) and by education (primary v tertiary).

The research question posed in this study is whether it is possible for the domestic policymakers to concurrently achieve the objectives of high economic growth, improved employment levels and fair income redistribution, as stated in the most recent NDP-Vision 2030 directives, under the current constraint of fiscal austerities. This challenge can be formulated as an optimisation problem in which stimulation of high economic growth is the object­ive function that must be maximised under the constraints of fiscal austerity and poverty re­duction. Traditional econometric models like the vector autoregressive (VAR), vector error correction (VEC) and autoregressive distributive lag (ARDL) models have a common limitation in that they do not provide economy-wide solutions to the constrained optimisation problem. For this reason, the study employs a dynamic computable general equilibrium (CGE) model that is designed to solve constrained optimisation problems (Löfgren, 2002). Given the South African context of poverty and inequality among the marginalised group of people and side-lined areas, the study makes use of a social accounting matrix (SAM), a tool that shows how income is generated in the economy and how that income is redistributed.

Besides the limitations of econometric models in solving constrained optimisation problem, previous economy-wide empirical studies on the South African economy (see Mabugu et al. (2013), van Wyk et al. (2014), Erero and Gavin (2015), Eroro (2016), Herault (2006) and Bonga-Bonga et al. (2016)) rely on a variety of input-output (I-O), Supply and Use (SUT), SAM and CGE models to assess the effect of government strategies on socio-economic variables and yet fail to reflect the dynamics of selected marginalised groups of people and marginalised areas. This is a noteworthy hiatus in the current literature since poverty and inequality remain high amongst previous disadvantaged population and have not been reversed even after 20 years of democracy. Ideally, the analys­is of poverty and inequality must cover the economy-wide dynamics of racial, gender, age dispa­rities and spatial incongruences. Moreover, disparities between urban and non-urban, formal and informal, skilled and unskilled are prominent in South Africa and the impact assessment must quantify how these variables respond to changes in government spending. Quantifying the impact of expansionary fiscal policy on vulnerable group of people is critical for monitoring progress of ‘inclusive economy’ strategy of the NDP. To achieve the research objectives set in this study, we run policy simulations on the SAM and the CGE models.

The remainder of the study is structured as follows. Section 2 presents the methodological framework. It discusses different functional forms underpinning the behavioural equations of eco­nomic agents in a CGE model, how the model was calibrated, and highlights the macro-closures in the model. Section 3 presents the micro-simulation results from the SAM. Section 4 presents the simulations from the CGE model. Section 5 concludes the study with policy implications.



2. Methodological Framework

The study employs Statistics South Africa (StatsSa) 2015 Supply and Use Tables (SUT’s) as input data to compile a new SAM. The methodology used in this study is consistent with the latest 2008 System of National Accounts (SNA, 2008) released by the United Nations and hence our constructed SAM-Leontief models comply with international best practices (United Nations, 2009). The employment multipliers were computed in line with the international Labour organisation recommendations (ILO, 2015). The standard SAM was extended to include external matrices that disaggregate households by race (African, white, Coloured, and Indian), employ­ment by age (youth and adults), education (primary v tertiary), and by areas (urban and non-urban) for micro-simulation pur­poses (Quantec Research, 2012). This uniqueness sets this study’s model apart from other economy-wide simulation models found in the previous South African literature (i.e. Mabugu et al. (2013), van Wyk et al. (2014), Erero and Gavin (2015), Eroro (2016), Herault (2006) and Bonga-Bonga et al. (2016)). Hence, the CGE was calibrated with a recent and modified SAM which better represents current structures and dynamics of the South African economy.

Transitioning from SAM to CGE was achieved by including a Cobb-Douglas production function, the constant elasticity of transformation (CET), the constant elasticity of substitution (CES), and on the other side, by incorporating the behaviour of institutions like households, government and private firms into the CGE model (Humphrey, (1997). Following the standard CGE model developed by Löfgren et al (2001), we construct­ a dynamic CGE model to use for policy analysis. The model is solved through a set of linear and non-linear equations using GAMS software. The model was calibrated from the disaggre­gated 2015 SAM. The data used in the model comprised mainly of the disaggregated SAM, other sets of income elasticities for households and commodities, trade elasticity for commodities, and external matrices four households and labour. The economic optimisation behaviour and the production and consumer decisions were captured by parameters, through optimising first-order conditions subject to a set of constraints. Incorporating the SAM into the CGE model enabled trans­fer of these structural and optimisation behavioural features into the CGE model, hence making it an applied CGE model. Adding time dimensions, and a set of time series elasticities, further converts it into a dyn­amic CGE model (Taylor and Black, 1974).

As background to CGE modelling, it is important to understand how goods and services are produced, and how industries and institutions interact in the economy. The CGE literature re­fers extensively to what is known as the multi-level or nested production function, which combines capital (K) and labour (L) as factor inputs. The CGE model comprises a set of behavioural equations that first need to be specified, then solved numerical­ly and simultaneously. The specification is instrumental to the type of solution anticipated in the model and hence CGE modellers are confronted with the task of linking the behavioural equation to the true functioning of the economy to be analysed as accurately as possible (Hum­phrey, 1997). Since the CGE model requires reconciling the behaviour of different sectors for a general equilibrium solution, the functional form representing the behaviour of different eco­nomic agents is discussed in this paper along with the appropriate institutions, factors and spe­cific economic sectors of the South African economy (Kehoe, 1998).

Household optimisation behaviour: The household aims to sell its endowed factors to the firms to earn income in the form of wa­ges and salaries. Households also derive other income in the form of rent or interest from the supply of capital. From all income received, households will spend the money on certain com­modities of their choice. The household is assumed to choose the consumption that maximises their utility, and in this case, it is assumed that the utility function (Equation 1) is the Cobb–Douglas type presented as follows (Boehringer et al, 2003):

U = Ac Ac (1)

Where Ac is a scaling parameter, Ci consumption of the ith good (Ci 0) and the exponent parameters ai are the share of each good in expenditure on consumption so that a1 + … + an = 1. At this stage, prices of goods and factors are assumed to be given in the household utility maximisation problem. Defining demand price of the ith good ( 0), price of the hth factor ( ≥ 0), Fh endowments of the hth factor for the household, Uh household utility function and αi share parameter in the utility function (0 αi 1), the household maximises its utility (i.e. Uh (C1 + … + Cn ) = ) subject to its balanced budget constraint in this manner Ci = Fh, with the Lagrange multiplier solution, ϕ, defined as:

L (Ci ; ϕ) = + ϕ ( Fh - Ci ) (2)

Firms or producer optimisation behaviour: The firms have one single objective, that is to maximise profit. The firm’s total cost is made up of two input costs (intermediate cost and factor cost) and maximise profit πj by choosing levels of intermediate inputs Xij and primary factors Vij to produce output Yi, subject to the constraint of its production technology φj (Boehringer et al, 2003). In other words we maximize πj = Pj Yj - - subject to Yi = φj (X1j , …, XNj ; V1j , …, VFj ). Note that one can also maximise its profits πj subject to its production technology con­straint φj under given output Yi and only the factor input Fh,j i.e. Maximise πj = Yj - subject to Yj = φj . This optimisation problem can be solved using the Lagrange multiplier δj defined as:

Lj(Yj ; Fh,j ; δj) = ( Yj - + δj ( φj - Yj) (3)

Market-clearing conditions in the CGE model: The optimisation problems explained so far have shown how households and firms determine their demand and supply of goods and factors due to their optimisation behaviour, which at this stage is not dependent on other agents’ decisions but only on the given good and factor prices (Boehringer et al, 2003). Firstly, there is no guarantee that the prices assumed by the households are the same as those assumed by the firms. Secondly, there is no guarantee that total supply will necessarily be equal to total demand for each good and for each factor in the economy. So, to ensure the market equilibrium of each good and factor in terms of quantity and price, it was necessary to impose the following market clearing conditions in the CGE model:

The CGE analysis mimics the real economic world and treats all markets simultaneously, and the effect of a policy shock in a specific market is translated to other markets (Donzelli, 2006). In reality, actions in one market are transmitted to other markets. Similarly, actions in one institution are conveyed to other institutions as well as other markets. For example: an in­crease in households’ income through compensation of employees (wages and salaries) will affect taxes received by government (pay-as-you earn = PAYE tax). As households spend the additional income on goods and services, firms will react by increasing production output to meet the new demand. Both households and firms will pay VAT for each item purchased. These interactions between markets and institutions are well modelled in the CGE which is categorized among tools suited for general equilibrium analysis (Luenberger, 1995). A CGE framework is considered as an economy-wide model that includes feedback between demand, income and production structure, and where all prices adjust until decisions made in produc­tion are consistent with decisions made in demand (Dervis and Robinson, 1982).

CGE and macroeconomic closure rules: As in econometric models, exogenous variables and exogenous variables within the CGE model must be chosen carefully. The choice is more complex in CGE models because these models often contain more variables than equations, implying that some variables must be kept out­side the model as exogenous variables; while the remainder of the variables are determined by the model as endogenous variables. The choice of which variables are to be exogenous is called the model closure rules or macroeconomic adjustment rules (Shoven and Whalley, 1984, 1992).

In selecting macro closure rules, the study attempted not to deviate much from the anatomy and structure of South Africa’s economy. For example, the determination of factor market clo­sures was guided by the realities in the labour market, such as the oversupply of unskilled labour and undersupply of highly-skilled labour. The factor market closures used in this study assumed that tertiary-educated workers (highly skilled labour) is fully employed and activity specific. It assumed that the unemployment rate is high among people with less than primary education (low-skilled labour), hence the factor market closure allows for mobility of these factors of production. As far as the CGE model is concerned, this type of factor market closures implies that the change in the supply of labour will occur in the low-skilled category, but not in the high-skilled labour category. Also, it is assumed that the wage rate of low-skilled labour is fixed at real wage level. The real wage was included in the model as the initial wage level multiplied by the consumer price index relative to the initial CPI level.

The model also assumed that capital is fully employed and activity-specific such that both capital and highly skilled labour may not move between activities. For fully employed factors, the wage lev­els will vary to clear the market. The model assumed a savings-driven investment closure, which implies that the savings level will determine investment. This savings-driven investment closure is supported by Herault (2006), who argued that the marginal propensity to save will be fixed for all non-government institu­tions, while capital formation is flexible. It is assumed that government instruments (like tax rates) are regarded as exogenous variables. The CPI published by Statistics SA was considered in this model as the numeraire.

Expansionary fiscal policy within the CGE refers to government spending regarding three items: govern­ment final consumption expenditure, government spending on its investment, and government transfer payments. In terms of financing mechanism, the model has assumed a balanced budg­et. As the government increases its investment spending and transfers to households, it is anti­cipated that demand for goods and services in the economy will rise, firms will respond to the increased demand by producing more output and employ more people. Newly employed peo­ple receive wages and salaries, others are beneficiaries of government transfers. Household in­come will be spent, creating second waves of demand for goods and service. Again, firms will respond to the increased demand by producing more output and employ more people. Conse­quently, tax on commodities will increase, VAT will increase, and household income tax, pay-as-you-earn (PAYE) tax will also increase to compensate for the new spending. In this way, the gov­ernment cannot run into a budget deficit, making fiscal policy sustainable over time.



3. Microsimulations Based on SAM Model

We firstly calibrate the economy-wide SAM-Leontief multiplier-based model to assess the extent to which an injection of government expenditure exerts on different demographic populations of the economy. To this end, three policy microsimulations were run with the SAM. The first scenario presents a simulation of the effect of an additional R100 income on households disaggregated by race (African, White, Coloured and Indian) and further classified these households into 12 income deciles representing low-income (decile 1-4), middle-income (decile 5-9) and high-income (decile 10-12) households. The findings from these simulations are reported in Table 1. Under the second and third scenarios, the SAM was extended by constructing an external matrix that disaggregated employment according to age group (i.e. youth (15-34 years) versus adults (35-64 years)) and area types (i.e. urban versus non-urban areas) for 10 strategic sectors (i.e. Agriculture, Mining, Manufacturing, Electricity, Construction, Trade, Transport, Finance, Community Services and General Government) and then simulated the model with a R1 million fiscal injection. We then asses the economy-wide effect on employment creation for youth versus adults (Scenario 2) and urban versus urban (Scenario 3) across the 10 sectors and plot the computed Leontief multipliers in Figures 1 and 2, respectively.

The simulation results from the first scenario reported in Table 1 shows that from a R100 injection by government into the economy has high disparities amongst the different race and income groups. We summarize these findings as follows. Firstly, Coloured (R5.88) and Indian (R 7.19) households receive the smallest gains from the fiscal injection whereas White (R48.66) and African (R38.27) households receive the greatest gains. Secondly, low-income (R7.50) and middle class (R29.14) households across all population groups receive the smallest portions from government spending whilst high-income households (R63.17) receive the highest share. Lastly, white, high-income households dominated all sub-population groups receiving a share of R42.39 per R100 fiscal injection whereas Coloured and White low-income households received the lowest share at R0.07 and R0.13, respectively.

On the other hand, the simulation outcomes for Scenarios 2 and 3 as summarized in Table 2, respectively, reveal that fiscal expansion in all strategic sector favours adult employment more than it does for youth employment (Scenario 2) as well as favouring employment in urban areas compared to non-urbanized areas (Scenario 3). To demonstrate the extent of disparities between youth and adult employment multipliers note that the third lowest sectoral employment multiplier for adults (i.e. 4.633 in Manufacturing) is larger than highest sectoral employment multiplier for youth employment (i.e. 4.624 in Trade). Also note that the government sector – the biggest em­ployer accounting for more than 22% of total employment in the country – will generate 2.826 jobs for the youth against 5.783 jobs for adults. We further observe youth employment multipliers are highest in the trade sect­or, followed by the community services sector. This implies that increasing government spend­ing will create jobs for the youth mainly in the wholesale and retail trade sector. In contrasting the employment multipliers for urban versus non-urban areas for scenario 3 as depicted in Figure 2, we also note that the second lowest sectoral employment multiplier for adults (i.e. 4.633 in Mining) is larger than highest sectoral employment multiplier for youth employment (i.e. 4.624 in Agriculture). In urban areas, employment multipliers are high in three sectors: communi­ty services, finance and trade, whereas in non-urban areas, employment multipliers are high in the agriculture sector.



Table 1. The Distribution of an Additional R100 Fiscal Injection on Different Race and Income Households

Income class

Income group

African

Coloured

Indian

white

Total

Total (RSA)

low

(poor)

Inc. 1

1.45

0.01

0.08

0.00

1.55

7.50

Inc. 2

1.10

0.01

0.06

0.02

1.19

Inc. 3

1.70

0.02

0.13

0.03

1.87

Inc. 4

2.53

0.03

0.25

0.08

2.90

middle class

Inc. 5

2.53

0.03

0.24

0.09

2.89

29.14

Inc. 6

2.99

0.06

0.29

1.18

4.52

Inc. 7

3.67

0.14

0.53

1.23

5.57

Inc. 8

4.07

0.29

0.68

1.13

6.17

Inc. 9

5.01

0.77

1.69

2.51

9.98

high (rich)

Inc. 10

5.53

1.33

0.61

5.39

12.86

63.37

Inc. 11

4.45

1.35

1.54

11.20

18.54

Inc. 12

3.23

1.85

1.09

25.80

31.97

Total (RSA)

38.27

5.88

7.19

48.66

100.00

100.00

Source: Micro-simulation results from the RSA SAM Model, 2015

Table 2. Summary of Employment Elasticities from Scenarios 2 and 3

Sector

Scenario 2 (Figure 1)


Scenario 3 (Figure 3)


Youth

Adult


Urban

Rural

Agriculture

4.042

6.379


6.396

4.624

Mining

2.570

3.920


4.633

1.857

Manufacturing

3.262

4.854


6.058

2.061

Electricity

2.030

3.263


3.951

1.342

Construction

4.148

5.649


7.380

2.417

Trade

4.674

6.344


8.517

2.501

Transport

3.722

5.270


7.174

1.817

Finance

4.014

6.763


9.010

2.467

Community services

4.460

7.186


8.937

2.704

General government

2.826

5.234


6.110

1.950

Total (weighted by output)

3.907

5.783


7.355

2.335

Source: Micro simulation results from the RSA SAM Model, 2015



4. Macrosimulations Based on Dynamic CGE Model

This section of the paper presents the three policy simulations run on the contemporaneous dynamic CGE model to assess the effect of expansionary fiscal policy on the macroeconomy. The first CGE simulation (Scenario 4) examines the economy-wide impact of public expenditure on i) demand-side components of economic activity ii) GDP at market prices and iii) the Gini coefficient. The second CGE simulation (Scenario 5) evaluates the impact of fiscal expansion on the household consumption patterns for the 12 deciles of income groups. The third CGE simulation (Scenario 6) evaluates the impact of fiscal expansion on employed people with different levels of educational attainment (i.e. primary, middle, secondary and tertiary). Tables 3, 4 and 5 report the simulation results for scenario 4, 5 and 6, respectively, and within these tables the effect of a 5% increase in government spending is reported in panel A whereas the effect of a 10% increase in government spending is presented in panel B. The reported results quantify the effect of these two shocks which are reported as percentage changes between the values in the baseline run (2015) and the policy run (2018, 2019, 2020) for each variable.

Starting with the results from the first CGE simulation (Scenario 4) in Table 3, we note that both a 5% and 10% fiscal shock improves investment and transfer payments to households with the effect being higher in investment than on household consumption throughout the policy run periods of 2018 to 2020. These results are not surprising as governments tends to invest in infrastructure that improves conditions for businesses to create value and develop innovative business ideas (Decaluwé et al., 2005). These, in turn, exert spillover effects to the trade sector as reflected by increased import and export activity. Further note that the effect of government spending on GDP is positive but minute and these findings are comparable to those in Mabugu et al. (2013) who similarly find South African expansionary fiscal policy to have a positive but very slight effect on GDP. Another interesting result from the model is that government spending contributes positively (but close to zero) to the reduction of income inequality, measured by the Gini coefficient. However, this effect is very small and almost negligible, with the percentage reduction in inequality being below 0.00% from 2018 to 2020.

In turning to the results for the second CGE simulation (Scenario 5) in Table 4, we observe fiscal spending to exert a positive effect on all household income deciles, although this effect is more pronounced for NON-POOR house­holds (deciles 1-4) than it is for POOR households (i.e. deciles 5-10). For example, with a 5% increase in government spending, POOR households’ consumption expenditure increases by 0.0301% compared with 0.0685% of their counterpart NON-POOR households’ consumption expenditure in 2018 and, in 2020, it rises slightly to 0.0362% and to 0.0832% respectively for POOR and NON-POOR households. These findings obtained from the CGE model are in perfect harmony with those obtained from the SAM model and knitting these results together suggests that in­come is still unevenly distributed, and consequently the gap between poor and rich is not nar­rowing. It can be thus concluded that the current fiscal expansion favours the rich households more than the poor households.

In the last CGE simulation (Scenario 6) in Table 5, we observe that an increase in government spending would contribute to creating jobs in favour of low-skilled as compared to high-skilled labourers. For instance, a 5% (10%) fiscal shock in 2018 is associated with a high employment growth rate of 0.0515% (0.1091%) among employees with primary education levels (low-skilled) compared with 0.0194% (0.0374%) among employees with tertiary education levels (high-skilled). The effect is positive and pro­gressive, rising by 0.0429% (0.1084%) between 2018 and 2019 for employees with pri­mary education levels. Our results are expected since South Africa’s labour market is overpopulated with low-skilled labour, which does not contra­dict the type of factor market closures in the CGE model that allow for mobility of factors of produc­tion in the low-skilled category. Hence, a change in the supply of labour will occur in the low-skilled category, while the labour market for high skilled workers is assumed to be fully em­ployed and activity-specific. The inference drawn from this simulation is that, in transitioning into the fourth industrial revolution, government spending should be strategically geared toward creating more jobs in the high-skilled category as low-skill routine jobs redundant and obsolete due to rapid changes in technology.

Table 3. Macroeconomy-Wide Effects of 5% and 10% Fiscal Injection



Panel A:

5% fiscal injection

Panel B;

10% fiscal injection

variables

Base (2013) R billion

2018

2019

2020

2018

2019

2020

ABSORP

3 158

0.0058

0.0678

0.1349

0.0089

0.1014

0.2016

PRVCON

2 410

0.5690

0.4519

0.3440

0.8535

0.6782

0.5171

FIXINV

827

0.7012

0.6895

1.6743

1.5510

1.9337

2.0109

GSTOCK

-5

0.0000

0.0000

0.0000

0.0000

0.0000

0.0000

GCONS

828

0.0018

0.0543

0.1031

0.0028

0.0814

0.1543

EXP

1 229

0.2984

0.3713

0.4379

0.4477

0.5570

0.6565

IMP

1 273

0.2876

0.3573

0.4206

0.4314

0.5358

0.6306

GDP

3 063

0.0059

0.0685

0.1363

0.0090

0.1024

0.2036

GINCOME

905

0.0006

0.0743

0.1416

0.0009

0.1112

0.2118

GINI

0.63

-0.0048

-0.0047

-0.0045

-0.0072

-0.0071

-0.0067

Source: Simulation results from the CGE model, 2015

Table 4. Effects of 5% and 10% Fiscal Injection of on Households Disaggregated by Income Level

Households

Base

(2013)

Panel A:

5% fiscal injection

Panel B;

10% fiscal injection



R billion

2018

2019

2020

2018

2019

2020

POOR

415

0.0301

0.0323

0.0362

0.0843

0.0904

0.1013

10% of population - 1st decile


41


0.0106


0.0189


0.0277


0.0295


0.0527


0.0772

10% of population - 2nd decile


71


0.0124


0.0196


0.0284


0.0342


0.0540


0.0781

10% of population - 3rd decile


87


0.0232


0.0254


0.0309


0.0669


0.0731


0.0889

10% of population - 4th decile


99


0.0318


0.0376


0.0382


0.0863


0.1020


0.1036

10% of population - 5th decile


117


0.0355


0.0395


0.0424


0.0969


0.1078


0.1157

NON-POOR

1 995

0.0685

0.0788

0.0832

0.1971

0.2269

0.2397

10% of population - 6th decile


135


0.0407


0.0512


0.0593


0.1137


0.1430


0.1656

10% of population - 7th decile


164


0.0426


0.0516


0.0603


0.1158


0.1404


0.1639

10% of population - 8th decile


229


0.0551


0.0632


0.0691


0.1476


0.1693


0.1851

10% of population - 9th decile


436


0.0582


0.0647


0.0739


0.1573


0.1747


0.1994

5% of population - 10th decile


514


0.0673


0.0771


0.0806


0.1898


0.2173


0.2271

1% of population - 10th decile


64


0.0696


0.0805


0.0859


0.1934


0.2238


0.2387

1% of population - 10th decile


74


0.0718


0.0839


0.0911


0.2024


0.2366


0.2570

1% of population - 10th decile


90


0.0743


0.0878


0.0924


0.2076


0.2455


0.2583

1% of population - 10th decile


109


0.0862


0.0907


0.1017


0.2410


0.2536


0.2843

1% of population - 10th decile


178


0.0867


0.1075


0.1208


0.2705


0.3062


0.3614

ALL HOUSEHODS

2 410

0.0504

0.0582

0.0671

0.1409

0.1625

0.1874

Source: Simulation results from the CGE model, 2015

Table 5. Effects of 5% and 10% Fiscal Injection of on Employment Disaggregated by Education

Employment category

Base (2013)

Panel A: 5% fiscal injection

Panel B; 10% fiscal injection



R billion

2018

2019

2020

2018

2019

2020

Employed with primary education

3 696

0.0515

0.0944

0.0944

0.1091

0.2013

0.2175

Employed with middle-education

5 969

0.0456

0.0664

0.0785

0.0911

0.1327

0.1569

Employed with secondary education

4 029

0.0296

0.0365

0.0408

0.0596

0.0734

0.0820

Employed with tertiary education

1 996

0.0194

0.0249

0.0286

0.0374

0.0480

0.0552

Source: Simulation results from the CGE model, 2015

5. Conclusions

Overcoming poverty, inequality unemployment in the post-global recession era has saturated public policy debates in South Africa and fiscal intervention is considered as the most effective domestic tool towards addressing these challenges. Our study uses a partial general equilibrium approach to assess the effectiveness of government expenditure on performing its dual obligation of improving economic growth and income distribution, on one hand, and reducing poverty, inequality and unemployment, on the other hand. We use Statistics South Africa (StatsSA) 2015 SAM to construct an economy-wide Leontief multiplier base model, micro-simulation, and a dynamic CGE model and we use these models to calibrate the effect of expansionary fiscal policy on the general macroeconomy as well as on marginalised group of people contrasted by age (Youth v Adult), race (African v non-African), income (less privileged v privileged households), education (primary v tertiary), and by area (Urban v non-urban). To reach our research objectives we performed a total of six microsimulations with three based on the SAM and the other three based on the CGE.

The findings from our microsimulations can be summarized as follows. From the first simulation we find discrepancies in the distribution of fiscal expenditure across racial groups with rich, ‘white’ households benefiting the most and poor ‘coloured’ households benefiting the least. We also observe a greater ‘income-gap’ more than ‘racial-gap’ across South African households. Our second simulation shows how fiscal injections benefit the adult employment more than it benefits youth unemployment. The third simulation further shows fiscal injections create employment in urban areas more than it does in rural areas. The fourth simulation demonstrates on how government injections exert very small economy-wide effects on improving economic output and the Gini coefficient. The fifth simulation demonstrates the economy-wide discrepancies in the effect of government spending across different income groups, with richer households benefiting much more from such expenditure compared to poor households. The last simulation demonstrates how fiscal injections improve employment for low-skilled labourers with low educational attainment as opposed to high-skilled labourers with more education.

Our simulations demonstrate why, after 20 years of democracy, inequality and poverty in the country has remained among the highest in the world, as government spending has exerted a minimal effect on historically marginalised groups of people and marginalised areas. Our simulations explain why there has been a tortoise pace in government’s efforts to reduce poverty and inequality through social expenditure programmes. The study hence recommends that governments should follow a priorities-based government spending policy which fits well with the current situation of the country. Furthermore, South Africa needs to adopt international standards and best practices of ‘science-based strategies’ rather than that of ‘evidence-based strategies’ and ensure that only programmes that have proved to be effective should be financed in the fiscal budget. Lastly, future government spending should be strategically geared towards creating more jobs in the high-skilled category so that the economy can respond to rapid changes in technology.


References

Boehringer, C.; Rutherford, T. & Wiegard, W. (2003). Computable General Equilibrium Analys­is: Opening a Black Box. ZEW Discussion Paper No 03-56. Mannheim: Zentrum für Europäische Wirtschaftsforschung (ZEW).

Bonga-Bonga, L.; Erero, J-L. & Gupta, R. (2016). Impact of Activity Tax in the Property Owning and Subletting of Fixed Property Sectors on the South African Economy: A CGE Analysis. Journal of Real Estate Literature 24(2) 345-357.

Collins, A.; Ishizaka, A. & Snowball, J. (2019). Film production incentives, employment transformation and domestic expenditure in South Africa: visualizing subsidy effectiveness. International Journal of Cultural Policy 25(2) 204-217.

Decaluwé, L.; Savard, L. & Thorbecke, E. (2005). General Equilibrium Approach for Poverty Analysis: With an Application to Cameroon. African Development Review 17(2) 213-243.

Dervis, K.; de Melo, J. & Robinson, S. (1982). General Equilibrium Models for Development Policy. Cambridge University Press.

Donzelli, F. (2006). Walras and Pareto on the Meaning of the Solution Concept in General Equilib­rium Theory. International Review of Economics 53 491-530.

Erero, J. (2016. National minimum wage in South Africa: A computable general equilibrium model analysis. Economic Research Southern Africa (ERSA) Working Paper 650. November.

Erero, J. & Gavin E. (2015). The Impact of the Dividend Tax in South Africa: A Dynamic CGE Model Analysis. Economic Research Southern Africa (ERSA) Working Paper 544 August.

Humphrey T. (1997). Algebraic Production Functions and Their Uses Before Cobb-Douglas. Federal Reserve Bank of Richmond Economic Quarterly 83(1) 51-83.

ILO (2015).The employment dimension of infrastructure investments A guide for employment impact assessment. Employment Sector Employment Working Paper No 178. Geneva.

Kehoe. T. (1998). Social Accounting Matrices and Applied General Equilibrium Models. I Begg and S G B Henry (editors). Applied Economics and Public Policy. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press 59-87.

Herault, N. (2006). Building and linking a microsimulation model to a CGE model for South Africa. South African Journal of Economics 74(1) 34-58.

Löfgren, H.; Harris R. & Robinson, S. (2002). A standard computable general equilibrium (CGE) in GAMS: Microcomputers in policy research. International Food Policy Research Institute (IFPRI).

      Mabugu, R.; Robichaud, V.; Maisonnave, H. & Chitiga, M. (2013). Impact Of Fiscal Policy In An Intertemporal Cge Model For South Africa. Economic Modelling 31 775-782.

Quantec Research (Pty) Ltd (2012). South African standardised industry indicator database. Sources and description. Unpublished paper.

Shoven, J. & Whalley, J. (1992.). Applying General Equilibrium. Cambridge University Press.

Shoven, J. & Whalley, J. (1984). Applied General-Equilibrium Models of Taxation and Internatio­nal Trade: An Introduction and Survey. Journal of Economic Literature 22(3) 1007-1051.

Taylor, L. & Black, S. (1974). Practical general equilibrium estimation of resources pulls under trade liberalization. Journal of International Economics 4(1) 37-58.

United Nations (2009). A System of National Accounts 2008 (SNA 2008). Jointly published by Uni­ted Nations. European Commission. International Monetary Fund. Organisation for Economic Co-operation and Development. World Bank. New York.

van Wyk, L.; Saayman, M.; Rossouw, R. & Saayman, A. (2014). Regional economic impacts of events: A comparison of methods. South African Journal of Economic and Management Sciences 18(2) 155-176.

World Bank (2014). South Africa economic update: fiscal policy and redistribution in an unequal society. World Bank. Washington: DC.

1PhD, Nelson Mandela University, University Way, Summerstrand, South Africa; Address: PO Box 77000, Port Elizabeth, 6031, South Africa, E-mail: kambalek63@gmail.com.

2 Associate Professor, PhD, Nelson Mandela University, University Way, South Africa; Address: PO Box 77000, Port Elizabeth, 6031, South Africa, Corresponding author: phiricandrew@gmail.com.

AUDŒ, Vol. 16, no. 2/2020, pp. 31-45